If Japan doesn't change course, it will have a major crisis within the next decade.Is Japan set to lead after 20 years of torpor?
If. But what people need to understand is, the Japanese government does have the power to avert a crisis. It is not inevitable.
There is one way that the crisis can definitely be averted: Raise taxes. Japan's fiscal woes can be boiled down to one sentence: Japan has European levels social spending and European levels of aging with American levels of taxation. But this could change; if Japan raised taxes to European levels, crisis would be instantly averted. According to analyses I've seen, this would require raising Japan's taxes from their current level of 32.5% of GDP to somewhere between 40% and 50% of GDP. That's comparable to France or Sweden. Painful, but not impossible.
Now for the rumor (rumor always being a large component in Western analyses of Japan). My sources at the Bank of Japan and Ministry of Finance tell me that domestic Japanese investors are betting that, after all the grumbling and fighting and ending of political careers, Japan's government will suck it up and raise taxes. This, my shadowy sources say, is why pension funds are still willing to put the Japanese people's money into JGBs.
But this story is not really outlandish. It's similar to what we're observing in America right now. U.S. borrowing is at all-time highs, but demand for Treasuries shows no sign of flagging, and most of that demand - more than in the past - is from domestic U.S. investors. Yes, we have shown a reluctance to raise taxes - witness the apocalyptic debt ceiling fight from last year. But if the public really thought the U.S. government was willing to default, domestic Treasury buyers would be heading for the exits. That they are not heading for the exits probably indicates that they believe that when push comes to shove, the U.S. government will suck it up and raise taxes. There are signs that the Republicans are quietly recognizing the necessity of this. At this point, it's just a fight between Democrats and Republicans to see who takes the fall for raising taxes - that's what the "fiscal cliff" is really all about.
Japan seems to be in a similar situation. It is not really unusual or outlandish at all. Everyone in the country still seems to believe that the government will continue to function. The day that that belief falters - or is proven wrong by main force, when interest payments swamp the primary budget - is the day that Japan collapses (the same goes for the U.S.). But if Japan's government is less dysfunctional than the often skittish Western press believes, that day will never come.
(Anyway... oh yeah, I did mention that there might be two ways out of Japan's fiscal trap, didn't I? The other way is to use monetary policy to create negative real interest rates for a very long period of time. If that can be done in a stable way (without accelerating inflation) and if stable growth persists, then Japan can use an "inflation tax" to erode the value of its government debt instead of an actual tax. Econ bloggers (and commenters), who tend to believe that central banks can hit any NGDP target they want, will probably advocate this "solution"...)
But while a revolution is under way in the attitude to economic targets, the new tools and instruments required to hit these targets have hardly begun to be discussed. The unemployment and GDP targets suggested by Bernanke and Carney are empty promises in the absence of policy tools that could convincingly boost jobs and growth in the present deflationary environment. Which is where Japan comes in.This election may be different in Japan
No other economy has (yet) suffered anything like Japan's 20 years of economic stagnation. It would not be surprising, therefore, if truly radical measures to deal with deflation were pioneered in Japan. Outside Japan, no central banker or politician has yet gone beyond pumping money into bond markets through quantitative easing. And nobody has suggested, at least officially, that central banks should directly lend to governments or finance one-off tax cuts.
The Japanese election on 16 December is attracting intense interest in the global financial markets. In part, this is because the LDP's election campaign, led by Mr Shinzo Abe, is based on forcing an entirely new monetary strategy on the Bank of Japan, with obvious consequences for the yen and the equity market.A Conversation with Ray Dalio
On top of that, the Japanese election is the first in a major democracy where the role and mandate of the central bank has taken centre stage in a national political campaign. Is this the shape of things to come in other democracies facing low growth, subdued inflation and rising government debt ratios? Politicians in many other developed economies will be watching the Japanese experiment with rapt attention...
As the population ages, the savings ratio will fall further, and the government will be forced to look overseas for the financing of its rising debt burden. An important recent study by Takeo Hoshi and Takatoshi Ito concludes that this is likely to result in a government debt crisis well within a decade. Markets are forward looking, and will see this coming well in advance.
Japan has defied the debt crisis doom-mongers for more than a decade now, but its long term deteriorating trends on demography, government debt and export performance cannot be held at bay indefinitely. Shinzo Abe has concluded that the only way out of this dilemma is to force the Bank of Japan to raise the inflation rate and (though he does not say this specifically) push the yen down. Unsterilised purchases of foreign assets may be the only way the central bank can do this.
Of course, there are severe risks with the Abe programme. If inflation expectations rise, bond yields may follow suit, undermining the capital base of the financial sector which holds all the bonds. But the Japanese political wind is now blowing strongly in the direction of co-opting the central bank as an integral arm of the government. If Mr Abe does not do it, someone else almost certainly will.
I give the example of Japan because when you're looking at the United States, the Japan example, I think, is a very good example. We have -- Japan has total debt-to-GDP of about 500 percent, and it has government debt-to-GDP of about 270 percent. So it is way, way, way more leveraged, in a sense, than the United States is. And so then the question is, as we go through this, the magnitude of monetization. You have to go back to say, who are the buyers of the debt and what are the motivations?Rational astrologies: "The process by which rational astrologies are chosen is the process by which the world is ruled. The United States is the world's financial power because it is conventional to pretend that the US dollar is a safe asset, and so long as it is conventional it is true and so the convention is very difficult to dislodge. Economics as a discipline has not performed very well from the perspective of commonsensical outside observers like the Queen of England. But the conventions of economic analysis are the rational astrology of technocratic government, and decisions that can't be couched and justified according to those conventions cannot be safely taken by policy makers. Policy is largely a side effect of the risk-averse behavior of political careerists, who rationally parade their adherence to this moment's conventions as enthusiastically as noblemen deferred to pronouncements of a court astrologer in an earlier time. We can only hope that our era's conventions engender better policy as a side-effect than attention to the movement of the stars. (As far as I am concerned, the jury is still out.) But it is not individuals' independent judgment of the wisdom of these conventions that guides collective behavior. Our behavior, and often our sincere beliefs, are largely formed in reaction to the terrifying accountability that comes with making consequential choices unconventionally. Our rational astrologies are at the core of who we are, as individuals and as societies."
There is a "greater fool" theory. The "greater fool" theory can go on for a really long time. The timing of when that shift takes place is very much dependent on that. So as we look in terms of, let's say, the United Sates, certainly it's the case -- and in Japan -- certainly it's the case that we can't support these kinds of debt. Anybody with a sharp pencil will know that we're not going to be able to support that. That doesn't mean there won't be adequate buy, just like in Japan's case. You can have plenty of buy. You provide enough liquidity, and the question is, what are the choices?
When the economic history of the 21st century is written, September 2012 is likely to be recorded as a defining moment, almost as important as September 2008. This month's historic events ¨C Ben Bernanke¡¯s promise to buy bonds without limit until the U.S. returns to something approaching full employment, Angela Merkel's support for the European Central Bank bond purchase plans and the Bank of Japan's decision to accelerate greatly its easing program ¨C may not seem earth-shattering in the same way as the near-collapse of every major bank in the U. S. and Europe. Yet the upheavals now happening in central banking represent a tectonic shift that could transform the economic landscape as dramatically as the financial earthquake four years ago.Japan, Corporate Profits, Kalecki and Living Standards - "Saying that the government's deficit is the non-government's surplus is only a slice of the overall story and really tells us very little about the overall health of the economy. It's more important to understand how domestic investment plays the primary role in how increases in living standards are generated."
To see why, we must go back in history 40 years, to the early 1970s. Maintaining full employment was at that time regarded as the main objective of all economic policy, and this had been the case for roughly 40 years, since the Great Depression. But by the early 1970s, voters had enjoyed decades of more or less full employment and were starting to focus on inflation rather than depression as the main threat to their prosperity. Economists and politicians were responding to this shift. Milton Friedman led a monetarist "counterrevolution" against the Keynesian obsession with unemployment, designing new economic models to challenge the Keynesian view that market economies were naturally prone to long-term stagnation. By restoring the pre-Keynesian assumption that market economies were automatically self-stabilizing, the monetarist models produced two powerful policy prescriptions directly opposed to the Keynesian views.
First, the monetarists insisted that price stability, rather than full employment, was the only legitimate target for monetary policy and government macroeconomic management more generally. Second, they argued that central bankers should not accept any direct responsibility for unemployment, since sustainable job creation depended solely on private enterprise ¨C full employment would be achieved automatically if inflation were conquered and market forces were allowed to operate freely, with the minimum of government interference or union constraints. A few years later, Margaret Thatcher and Ronald Reagan turned Friedman's intellectual revolution into practical politics. On top of its economic impact, monetarism had huge ideological effects by absolving government macroeconomic management of any direct responsibility for jobs and instead attributing unemployment to regulations, unions, welfare policies and other market distortions.
If the dollar takes a huge plunge, then rest assured that raising federal income taxes to 50% will not solve our problems.
Poland has been one of the world's great development success stories of the past two decades... If you want to understand why Poland had a good crisis, you need to understand three things. First, you need to know that Poland's currency, the zloty, was never pegged to the euro... Private credit growth was much slower in Poland, although it was still pretty rapid. Some of this was because of Poland's history with corporate nonperforming loans from the late 1990s and the early 2000s... Poland's institutions were relatively unfriendly to creditors...The Big Secret of Poland's Economic Success¡ªand What It Means for Us
In the absence of a currency peg, they were perfectly willing to make loans in zloty through their Polish subsidiaries. These inflows from the West caused the zloty to appreciate by more than 50% against the euro during the credit boom. While the strong currency made foreign-currency-denominated debt relatively more attractive to people who unwisely assumed that the zloty would continue to appreciate indefinitely, it may have dampened loan growth overall. The strong currency also provided flexibility to respond to a downturn.
Sure enough, when the crisis hit and Western European lenders started pulling their money out of Poland, the zloty lost more than a third of its value against the euro... the devaluation was unambiguously stimulative. Between the middle of 2008 and the beginning of 2009, Poland's trade balance swung from a deficit of more than €1.7 billion to a surplus of more than €100m. The trade balance returned to deficit as world trade rebounded, but at about €500m, it is now far smaller than it was...
Of course, the devaluation of the zloty would not have been sufficient to keep Poland out of recession had it not been for an act of flagrant government intervention into the private financial system: the Vienna Initiative. This is the second thing you need to know about to understand Poland's post-2008 performance. In one of the wiser acts of European policymaking, the Vienna Initiative encouraged Western European lenders to maintain their exposures to Central and Eastern Europe...
The last thing you need to understand about Poland is that it practised robustly counter-cyclical fiscal policy. During the boom years, its government budget deficit shrank from more than 6% of GDP to less than 2%. Then, in response to the downturn, the deficit ballooned to nearly 8% by 2011. The government explicitly rejected austerity and was the only nation on the European continent to avoid a recession.
Its GDP per capita, adjusted for purchasing power parity, has increased at an average annual rate of 5.1 percent since 2007 versus 1.4 percent a year for the U.S. over the same period. Now, the U.S. is much richer than Poland, so we would expect the latter to grow faster -- but not this much faster...also btw Russia is no longer in a demographic death spiral
It wasn't hard money that saved Poland. It was really, really, really easy money that saved Poland. Just look at the chart below of the exchange rate between the Polish zloty and the euro the past five years. That's a 33 percent drop starting in late 2008... A nice, big currency depreciation is as easy as easy monetary policy gets. It's what Princeton professor and deputy governor of Sweden's Riksbank Lars Svensson calls a "foolproof way" out of a liquidity trap -- when short-term rates are zero and central banks can't cut them any further. It's what Israel did in 2009 and Switzerland is doing today with its currency peg.
Over the past seven years, Russia's demographics have improved at a rapid clip. As data released today by Rosstat, the Russian state statistical agency, show, Russia is actually on track to record a small natural population increase in 2012. To understand just how dramatic a turnaround this is, it helps to look at a graph of the past two decades...(cf! Russia Is Finished & Inequality in Pre-Revolutionary Russia ;)
During the chaos of the 1990's, as the economy collapsed, living standards fell, and the state was unable to fulfill even its most basic obligations. Russia really did experience a withering demographic crisis. Consumed by insecurity and anxiety, Russians stopped having children and started to die at greatly elevated rates. The health system's disfunction played a role, but was secondary to a pervasive environment of psychosocial stress, heavy drinking, and poor nutrition. This was a humanitarian disaster on a grand scale that was almost totally unheralded in the West while it was taking place even as many Russians, such as dissident Aleksandr Solzhenitsyn, shouted themselves hoarse about the ongoing catastrophe.
However, over the past seven years there has been a decline in death rates from causes like murder, suicide, and alcohol poisoning, and the birth rate has increased. State efforts, such as the much heralded "maternal capital" program which gives almost $10,000 to parents having a second or third child, have had some impact. But most of the improvement is due to economic growth, increased wages, and a generally increased sense of normalcy and stability.
Russia will, like every other country in Europe, face demographic challenges: its population will continue to age, and major reforms to the pension system are clearly needed. But Russia is, thankfully, not in the midst of a "death spiral"¡ªwhen you account for substantial immigration, its "declining" population has actually been growing for most of the past four years.
The article tells readers that the share of the population over 65 is projected to rise from 25 percent in 2010 to 40 percent in 2050. Given that roughly 20 percent of the population is under age 20, this implies that the current ratio of people ages 20-65 to people over age 65 is approximately 2.2 to 1. Assuming the under 20 portion falls to 15 percent of the population by 2050, in that year the ratio will be 1.4 to 1.Also: "In short, the aging story is a joke."
If productivity growth averages just 1.5 percent annually (it has been averaging more than 2.0 percent in the U.S. over the last 15 years), then output per worker will be more than 80 percent higher in 2050 than it is today. If the average retiree currently consumes 70 percent as much as a prime age worker, then this increase in productivity would allow retirees in 2050 to enjoy a 50 percent rise in living standards above current levels, while still leaving workers almost 30 percent better off.
Ultimately, it takes two to make a monetary-based economy: investors and spenders. But it's the relative balance between these two parties that ultimately determines the cost of money and value of savings and investments.Closing the deficit is painless - "If closing the deficit and getting more revenue as a percent of GDP is all about growth, then why do we have to raise taxes on anyone? Here it's probably best to think of Fiscal Policy not as a tool to create revenue and close deficits, but as a tool to shape society by incentivizing some kind of activity (e.g. tax credits for R&D), disincentivizing other kinds of activity (sin taxes) and redistributing wealth (progressive taxation). All of this is controversial stuff, but there's almost nobody on either side of the political spectrum at this point who doesn't favor some kind of redistribution of wealth so as to ameliorate extreme inequality... One of the most important charts in the world is Richard Koo's look at what happened when Japan tried tightening fiscal policy prematurely during its slump and deficits widened. Pain is entirely the wrong way to think about closing the deficit. If it's important to make it go away, we need to find a way of doing the exact opposite, putting people to work and making the economy grow."
What we have now, unfortunately, is an economy overcome by "investors" looking to protect wealth, in a world that offers ever fewer risk-free opportunities outside the government sector.
And why is that? Because private alternatives are naturally riskier when diminishing capital returns are guaranteed to manifest more quickly due to the collaborative "free" effect. Indeed, unless you invest in an industry monopoly which is prepared to sue anyone who tries to compete in their field ¡ª often in a way that suspends or regresses technology ¡ª it's unclear whether the company in question will have enough time in the limelight to be able to return your capital, let alone interest, before it is obliterated by a market competitor or the collective collaborative base.
What's more, when so much is available for free in the market, who can actually be bothered to spend on stuff that, you know, costs something?
Think of it, perhaps, as entirely new "free" market.
« Older I shot 'im in the eye - dude didn't even blink... | A Map of Saints' Relics in Rome Newer »
This thread has been archived and is closed to new comments
posted by leotrotsky at 4:11 PM on December 27, 2012 [51 favorites]